Showing posts with label managed care cost effectiveness. Show all posts
Showing posts with label managed care cost effectiveness. Show all posts

Tuesday, October 1, 2013

What JAMA Psychiatry Doesn't Know About Patient Dumping

JAMA Psychiatry recently posted commentary on a form of patient dumping that I described in a previous post as Greyhound therapy.  The authors' post an impressive chart of state mental health budget cuts and some of the associated problems.  Their solution to the problem "opening a dialogue among providers, funding agencies, and Congress" is a non solution that suggests a lack of appreciation for the details of the problems and how the system of care for people with serious mental illnesses has been systematically dismantled and is no longer capable of providing quality or innovative psychiatric care.  To illustrate my point consider the following 8 points:

1.  The myth of dangerousness is all encompassing.  At some point the government and the managed care industry wanted to make the rationale for admissions to psychiatric units as difficult as possible to ration inpatient psychiatric care.  The standard question is: "Is this person a danger to themselves or anyone else."  This bias has completely disrupted inpatient care.  We now have desperate people who should have been admitted who are lying about suicidal ideation in order to get admitted.  We have people who don't need to be admitted saying they are suicidal and getting admitted.  The point is that this criteria is irrelevant for a whole range of indications for inpatient treatment.  As an example, anyone with a familiy member who has severe mental illness recognizes that there are times when they are completely unable to function due to their illness.  Leaving that person at home to fend for themselves in that condition is not only a bad idea it is inhumane and yet they may not meet somebody's criteria for "dangerousness".

2.  Length of stay in all community based psychiatric units is based on DRG payments.  That means there is a set reimbursement for a diagnosis related stay independent of how long the patient is in the hospital.  As an example a psychosis DRG is one of the commonest DRGs and the last reliable figure I have is that it pays $4,500 per DRG.  That is set by the federal regulatory agency for Medicare reimbursement but practically every managed care and insurance company pays the same way either per admission or per discharge.  If the patient stays 5 days that is nearly the mythical "$1,000/day" that most people believe the hospital is reimbursed.  If the stay is 30 days that is $150/day and less that the cost of most board and care homes.  This is a strong financial incentive for the hospital to discharge the patient as soon as possible.

3.  Despite an emphasis on biological treatments in inpatient settings, there really are no biological treatments that work in the 5 days.  That is the length of stay most hospitals want their patients discharged in.  Most inpatient experts will tell you that severe mental illnesses (as opposed to crisis intervention) often require at least 2 - 4 weeks for stabilization.

4.  Available social service providers have no incentive to assist the hospital with placement irrespective of whether there is adequate housing or not.  The hospital is the least expensive place to house the patient, even if they are stable for discharge.

5.  The economic incentives result in a large patient population that circulates from homelessness to emergency departments to inpatient care.   These same incentives result in the patient being exposed to no single environment that results in their stabilization.  In fact providing thousands of dollars of discharge medications to people who will probably never take them is a massive inefficiency that creates an illusion that inpatient treatment has done something.  My personal conversations and correspondence with many outpatient psychiatrists confirms that most of them consider inpatient care to be a complete waste of time and they acknowledge that they have no good place to send their patients anymore for stabilization.

6.  The same managed care companies that denied hospital claims many years ago currently own the facilities.  They now have case managers essentially running their inpatient treatment and telling the physicians there when a patient must be discharged.  If the doctors working in that environment don't go along they can be forced out or placed in an uncomfortable enough position that they quit.  Managed care companies frequently have proprietary and arbitrary guidelines that dictate when people are discharged.  It is not a coincidence that the suggested lengths of stay are expected to maximize profits and have nothing to do with quality psychiatric care.

7.  Utilization reviewers still exist.  Their job is basically to argue with inpatient physicians and harass them enough so that they discharge the patient.  These physicians were supposed to be "peers" but in my experience talking with them over the years, it was apparent that I was not talking with anyone who had actually worked in an inpatient unit.  Their job was clearly to force me to get the person out of the hospital or play the trump card by denying payment and getting the hospital to force me to get the patient out.  You might ask yourself why they are necessary if their company is paying a fixed fee for inpatient care and I think that is a good question.

8.  The trivial reimbursement for inpatient care deincentivizes access to other assessment and treatment modalities that the patient may need such as specialty consultation, brain imaging, and electroencepaholgraphy.  Patients may be told to come back for outpatient appointments when the treating psychiatrist knows that patient will not return for the necessary appointments and will probably be readmitted soon with the exact same medical problem.

All of these issues combined are why people are discharged to the street or put on a bus.  You can see that the common theme here is actually the rationing of services by the government and managed care industry as well as psychiatry's inability to deliver the quality of care that psychiatrists are trained to provide in this restricted environment.  The suggested solutions in the authors article seem to be written by Joint Commission bureaucrats and will have little impact.

This is a problem that can be solved by psychiatrists but it has to start with a quality approach.  Inpatient specialty training in psychiatry with a focus on providing state of the art assessment and care is necessary.  It is an ideal place to begin to attend to the cognitive dimension of psychotic disorders and mood disorders.  Civil commitment laws need to be reformed with a focus on treatment rather than dangerousness.  There needs to be an appropriate hand-off from the hospital team to  a community team and a housing team.   It is the time to stop demanding "cost effective" treatment from a system that has been practically rationed into non-existence.  It is time to invest in quality to the point that patients with severe mental illness and their families can expect that there will be psychiatric services available as a resource on par with the cardiology services they expect for any middle aged person with chest pain.

George Dawson, MD, DFAPA

1.  Das S, Fromont SC, Prochaska JJ. Bus Therapy: A Problematic Practice in Psychiatry. JAMA Psychiatry. 2013 Sep 25. doi: 10.1001/jamapsychiatry.2013.2824.  [Epub ahead of print] PubMed PMID: 24068366.

Tuesday, June 25, 2013

The Real Problem With Managed Care Research

You know the kind of research I am talking about.  The research that shows that managed care is more cost effective and higher quality than fee for service.  This stuff has been out there since the 1990s.  Is there really research like that out there or is it little more than a political exercise?  We have more than a few clues thanks to recent analysis of a Health Affairs article by Kip Sullivan.  The article is titled: "The ‘Alternative Quality Contract,’ Based On A Global Budget, Lowered Medical Spending And Improved Quality"  Sullivan points out that the title of this article is misleading because it suggests that the managed care intervention here "lowered medical spending and improved quality" in the title, but in the body of the work the authors state:

"Our findings do not imply that overall spending fell for Blue Cross Blue Shield of Massachusetts in 2009-2010."  

and a paragraph later:

"This result makes it likely that total Blue Cross Blue Shield payments to groups in 2010 exceeded medical savings achieved by the group that year."  

Sullivan's analysis here is dead-on, especially the idea that "medical savings" can be parsed from overall savings when there is suddenly a large managed care infrastructure.  From some of the places where I have worked, this means bringing in a raft of middle managers who provide no service and generate no income to "manage' the people who are actually providing the care.  In some settings that could mean a "manager" for every 5 - 10 physicians.   If your goal is to cut reimbursement to the providers by just paying them less or sending them fewer referrals while adding a costly overhead of a number of managers who think they can translate their ideas about business into better clinical care - that seems like a recipe for higher costs, record physician dissatisfaction, and disregard for professional quality based guidelines.  Sullivan points out that this specific problem in managed care research has been around since the 1990's

The "higher quality" issue is as interesting.     I encourage anyone interested to download the paper because it is only free until Sunday June 30.  As you read it, take a look at the table labeled "Exhibit 4".  It is a table of quality care measures across both the control groups and the intervention groups.  Although many of the variables are easily defined a couple of issues appear to be clear.  Many seem to be process variables.  In other words, just keeping track of variables and making sure that you are ticking them off gives you more credit.  This is standard procedure in a managed care environment with more case managers.  They can literally be assigned to remind physicians or ward teams to do tasks on a time frame that gives them credit for the process variable.  More administrative manpower should equate to a larger percentage of process variables.

I note that within the quality variables there are two that apply to psychiatry - Depression: Short Term Rx and Depression: Long Term Rx.  There are no significant differences across that study period at the P<0.05 level.  This is interesting at a couple of levels.  First, if this is actually the number of depressed people treated the change after the managed care intervention is not significant.  Secondly, what measures are used to make this determination.  Are these actually depressed people or are they patients scoring above a certain cutoff on a PHQ-9 rating scale?  Third, is the change in percentage of patients treated a legitimate quality marker?  Aren't we more interested in retention in treatment and actual treatment of individual patients treated into remission rather than a cross sectional look at the percentage of patients treated?

The scientific concerns about this paper are numerous.  Like all research (and I mean all research) there are political implications.  The defined intervention here of the Alternate Quality Contract, is basically a primary care physician as gatekeeper model that consumers rejected over a decade ago.  At that point in time, managed care organizations realized that they would need to compete on the basis of providing direct access to specialty care without primary care referrals.  The adaption of the MCOs was to hire their own specialists and build speciality clinics.  The article describes this as basically the "patient centered medical home" (p 1886).   I wonder if the average consumer realizes that the medical home is really a primary care gatekeeper system from the past?

I can't help stressing the importance of article like this one and all research that purports to save money with larger administrative structures that are there in a large part to supervise physicians rather than create administrative efficiencies.  There is no better example than the non-existent mental health system for what this kind of rationing and administrative excess can create.  Diverting money from the direct provision of clinical care into complicated forms of administrative overhead needs to be measured accurately in all of these studies.

George Dawson, MD, DFAPA